The Dismal State of Multilateral Development Finance
In view of the tremendous funding needs for
fighting global public bads - pandemics such as now the coronavirus, climate
change, hunger, analphabetism or terrorism – multilateral development finance
has since long been in bad shape. The multilateral development-finance system
has become overly complex. One would like to think that the system is an
orderly process guided by simple principles, but it is rather a non-system[1].
This non-system does not result from coherent design but is a child of
spontaneous disorder. A rising treat is the rise of ´multilateralism à la
carte` as large donors starve core budgets of UN agencies
Since the early 2000s, new actors, both
public and private, have emerged as important sources of finance, in addition
to MDBs, UN agencies and the bi-multilateral donor EU. The rise of emerging
powers as new lenders (notably China), the creation of so-called vertical funds[2]
to finance global health and other global commons, the growing role of
non-governmental organisations and the increased presence of private
philantropy are stressing the developing-country recipients. They complain
about the administrative burdens imposed on them by donor missions, evaluation
bureaucracies, policy dialogues and other strings attached to aid money.
The OECD has reviewed multilateral
development finance since 2008; those reports have failed to capture the wide
attention they deserve. Multilateral
Development Finance 2020, a very infomative 140-pages report, has been
published recently[3].
It provides a rich portrait of a system under stress. Its focus of attention
are ODA-eligible international organisations, mostly UN agencies, multilateral
development banks and “Vertical funds” - development financing mechanisms
confined to single development domains (such as health) with mixed private and public
funding sources.
In 2018, total funding to multilateral
organisations covered by the OECD report reached a new all-time high, at USD
71.9 billion[4].
However, multilateral funding is now primarily driven by a rise in earmarked
contributions – by some large countries cherrypicking the system. You could
argue that this reflects bilateral funding disguised as multilateral.
In particular UN agencies (such as WFP,
UNHCR or even UNCTAD) suffer from rising funding vulnerabilities, mostly a
result of a drop in the share of core contributions to their budget. A high
donor concentration (such as for IOM) can create such funding vulnerability as
well. Figure 1 presents the 2016-18 data for UN agencies, MDBs and Vertical
Funds[5].
Figure 1: Earmarking, Donor Concentration and Funding Vulnerability, 2016-18
Source:
OECD, Multilateral
Development Finance 2020
Who is
responsible (among large DAC donors) for the dismal state of multilateral
finance for ODA-eligible international organisations? Table 1 provides elements
for an answer. Two large donors need to be singled out: Germany and the United
States. The majority of their contributions to ODA-eligible multilaterals was increasingly
earmarked for programmatic or project-type purposes rather than allocated to
core budgets.
·
The United States has turned into an agressive cherrypicker of the
multilateral system, rather unsurprisingly for the past Trump administration,
but also before under Obama. During the period 2012 to 2018, the share of core
multilateral contributions in ODA provided by the US fell from 18% to 11%. It
will be worth watching whether President-elect Joe Biden is going to revert
that trend.
·
Germany is now among the worst
offenders, contrary to the country´s self image as the quintessential
multilateralist. The share of core multilateral contributions in Germany´s ODA
has dropped continuously over the 2010s, from 35% to round 20% of its ODA in
2017. Some may object that Germany is the biggest contributor to the EU, hence
more multilateral than visible from country sources. But as shown in Table 1,
the EU institutions don´t behave differently and contribute apparently little
to the core budgets of ODA-eligible multilateral agencies.
·
By contrast, France and the United Kingdom have maintained their core budget funding as a share
of ODA over the 2010s, France just below and the UK at around 40%. Italy, Spain
and Portugal support multilateral core funding most, in relation to their ODA
contributions (around 2/3).
Table 1: Top DAC Donors to ODA-Eligible Multilaterals, 2010s
Country |
Total USD bn, 2018 |
Trend from 2016 |
% to Core 2018 |
Trend 2010s |
United Kingdom |
11.3 |
↗ |
36.3 |
→ |
United States |
10.2 |
→ |
11.2 |
↘ |
Germany |
10.0 |
↗ |
22.0 |
↘ |
France |
6.1 |
↗ |
38.0 |
↗ |
Japan |
5.0 |
↗ |
23.0 |
→ |
Italy |
3.5 |
↗ |
56.8 |
↗ |
Canada |
3.4 |
↘ |
24.4 |
↘ |
Memo: EU |
4.4 |
↘ |
1.8 |
→ |
Source: OECD, Creditor Reporting
System (database); own calculations.
Earmarking is not bad per se. The rise of
earmarking may be attributable to the spike in humanitarian interventions of
the past decade, for example. Those interventions account for a large share of
the funding earmarked by DAC members through the multilateral development
system. But there are significant cost of ´multilateralism à la carte´, i.e.
multi-bi funding (earmarked bilateral aid routed via multilateral channels)[6]:
·
Multilateralism à la carte undermines
universality, which affords every country a voice regardless its size. Earmarking
may well imply less funding for so-called global public goods as it distorts
the balance between supply and demand. This has been seen to slow responses to
pandemics by UN agencies. Healing pandemics, such as the current coronavirus
crisis or the former Ebola crisis in West Africa, or ending hunger in refugee
camps (and elsewhere), are good examples of the need for a universal approach.
Multilateral work programmes risk to become less needs driven and country
choices distorted with rising donor domination.
·
The “tragedy of commons”[7]
is reinforced by earmarking via institutional hollowing out. This hollowing out
works in two related ways. First, staff and management attention and capacity
are increasingly pulled away from original core activities approved by the
broader membership. Second, power and accountability gradually shift away from
the broader collective as multilateral institutions increasingly become viewed
as a mere instrument to implement the spending choices of relatively few large
donors, leaving smaller countries as passive bystanders.
·
Long debates on the reform of
the Bretton Woods institutions have failed to restore representativeness to the
system; the G7 countries still dominate decision making. The challenge to find
ways to have small countries participate in global governance has not been
resoved by the creation of the G20 bureaucracies.
The election of US President-elect Joe
Biden gives some reason to hope for a return of the United States to some less
conditional multilateralism. Germany, traditionally a close ally of the US,
should step up contributions to core budgets of ODA-eligible agencies
simultaneously. The United Nations need to be strengthened after a lost decade.
A handle to speed up core contributions to the UN might be to link them to the
widely demanded rise of budget contributuions to NATO. Alas, while NATO has a
strong lobby with the arms industry, especially the American, the United
Nations have not.
[1] Helmut Reisen (2010), „The Multilateral Donor Non-System: Towards
Accountability and Efficient Role Assignment”, http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2010-5,
February.
[2] Stephen Browne and Roberto Cordon (2015), “Vertical
Funds: Lessons for Multilateralism and The UN”, Future United Nations
Development System, CUNY Graduate Center, Briefing 25, January.
[3] OECD (2020), Multilateral Development Finance 2020, https://doi.org/10.1787/e61fdf00-en.
[4] Ignore for a moment that the DAC has recently changed ODA reporting
rules to include transactions that require no financial sacrifice. This
deprives ODA of its meaning as a gauge of aid effort, and vitiates the point of
setting the U.N. ODA target. The changes have also rendered ODA incoherent as a
statistical measure, making it a faulty tool for monitoring and analysis. ODA
now fails to meet basic statistical quality standards. See Simon Scott (2018),
“A
note on current problems with ODA as a statistical measure”, Brookings,
September.
[5] The list of ODA-eligible international organisations currently
contains some 360 entries. It can be downloeaded as Excel file here https://www.oecd.org/dac/stats/annex2.htm.
[6] Owen Barder, Euan Ritchie, and Andrew Rogerson (2019), “Contractors
or Collectives?” Earmarked Funding of
Multilaterals, Donor Needs, and
Institutional Integrity: The World Bank as a Case Study, CGD
Policy Paper 153, Center for Global Development, July.
[7] Hardin, Garrett (1968). "The Tragedy of the Commons", Science, Vol. 162 (3859), pp. 1243–1248. The “tragedy
of the commons” denotes a situation in a shared-resource system where
individual users, acting independently according to their own self-interest,
behave contrary to the common good of all users by depleting or spoiling the
shared resource through their collective action. The original concept referred
to the effects of unregulated grazing on common land (also known as a
"common") in Great Britain and Ireland.
No comments:
Post a Comment