The OEEC
had been the European child of the Marshall Plan since 1948, the OECD was its
North Atlantic grandchild since 1961; the OECD Development Centre became its
South oriented late-birth. Founded in 1962 at the suggestion of US
President John F. Kennedy[1],
the semi-autonomous research-oriented institution was intended to serve as a
forum for the exchange of policy know-how and as a link between OECD members
and developing countries.
Despite
offers from the IMF (DC), Moody's (NYC), KfW (Ffm) and GIGA (HH), I remained
associated with the Development Centre in Paris for almost 29 long years[2],
from 12/1983 to 9/2010. This post recollects my 1980s at the Centre.
Both the
OECD and the OECD Development Centre probably had the best time behind them in
December 1983, when I started there. Secretary General Emile van Lennep had been highly regarded by the OECD economists
but was about to retire. He was a lawyer who was not a Do-It-Yourself economist and so enjoyed listening to his Economics
Department (all other departments were only entitled to refer to themselves as
Directorate). His Keynesian chief economist Stephen
Marris was someone who did not allow himself to be infected by the then
popular currents in economics (rational expectations; supply-side theory). A
typical agency problem that was often encountered in multilateral
organizations: the agent only apparently cared about the preferences of his
member countries, the principal[3].
In times of Reagan and Thatcher this could not go well for long.
The OECD
Development Centre had experienced its best period to this date thanks to the
British Deputy Director Prof. Ian M.D. Little[4]
(†2012) who during his short term of office (1966-68), gathered around him
market friendly British and Indian top economists (e.g. Jagdish Bhagwati,
Deepak Lal, Sir James Mirless (Nobel 1996), Tibor Scitovsky, Maurice Scott).
Two studies - Manual of Industrial Project Analysis II, Social Cost Benefit
Analysis (1969) and Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (1970) -
had a lasting, albeit controversial, influence on the development economics
literature[5].
When I joined the OECD Development Centre in December 1983, academic
orientation, liberalism and excellence had faded away, the key protagonists having
migrated mostly towards Nuffield College (Oxford U) and the World Bank.
The Centre
was thus market liberal during the Keynesian orientation of the OECD in the
1960s. Subsequently, the OECD gradually and belatedly shifted towards supply
side policy. Meanwhile, the Centre came increasingly under the influence of
small European OECD countries (Table 1) and moved into internal opposition to
the "main OECD” that was dominated by the US and the UK at the time. Giulio Fossi, who had joined the OEEC in 1949 and later the Centre in 1963, incarnated that opposition second to none. Responsable for external cooperation and aiming to link especially with NGOs active in the South, he was keen to counteract the OECD image as a rich man´s club. Closer to the Society for International Development (SID), Giulio despised bureaucratic censorship and defended researchers´ independence at the Development Centre.
Table 1: One female & six male heads of the OECD Development Centre,
from 1983
Period |
Development
Centre |
OECD |
Period |
1983-85 |
Justus Faaland
(†2017), N |
Emile van
Lennep (†1996), NL |
1969-84 |
1985-92 |
Louis Emmerij (†2019), NL |
Jean-Claude Paye, F |
1984-94 |
1993-99 |
Jean Bonvin (†2017),
CH |
Don Johnston,
Can |
1996-06 |
1999-03 |
Jorge Braga de Macedo, P |
|
|
2003-07 |
Louka Katseli,
Gr |
José Ángel
Gurría, Mex |
2006- |
2007-10 |
Javier Santiso, Esp |
|
|
2010- |
Mario Pezzini, I |
|
|
The
Norwegian Just Faaland, a former
concentration camp prisoner (Buchenwald 1943-45), became my first boss at the
OECD Development Centre; reluctantly, because I had published very little
academically until then and was arguably suspect to him as a German[6].
A student of the Nobel Prize winner Ragnar Frisch, Faaland was employed in 1949
by the OEEC in Paris, where Angus
Maddison and the later recipient (2005) of the Nobel
Prize, Tom Schelling, worked among
others. In 1952 he was appointed a member of the Chr. Michelsen Institute
(Bergen), where he later served as director for 28 years[7].
Prof. Faaland advised several countries and international organisations before
becoming President of the OECD Development Centre. For his advisory work on
Malaysia's multi-ethnic Bumiputra policy, Tan
Sri Just Faaland received the Merdeka Award in 2010.
Through
Faaland's mediation I soon got to know the Scottish bestselling author of the
Development Centre - the "chiffrephil" economic historian Angus Maddison[8]
- who had previously worked with the OEEC like Faaland. Since then Angus had
been commuting from his "electronic cottage" in northern France to
his chair at the University of Groningen and the OECD in Paris - unless he was traveling
through the big wide world to obtain historical output data. When we met at
lunch, Faaland and Maddison toasted Maggie Thatcher's future fall with
champagne. Cheekily, I had a glass of milk.
Prof. Christian Morisson joined the Centre in 1984; he would stay until 1994 as a head of research division. His appointment clearly brought back some academic spirit and Africa exposure to the Centre. With Prof. Christian Morrisson joining from Université de Paris 1 , the Centre slowly started to recover at least in academic perception; not yet, however, in esteem inside the OECD family. Christian Morrison also attracted as a nonresident Prof. François Bourguignon (later Chief Economist of the World Bank and then founding Rector PSE). Thus, before income inequality became a wildly popular subject of economics, Christian and François brought their expertise on global income distribution to the OECD Development Centre. (Cf. e.g. François Bourguignon & Christian Morrisson (1992), “Inequality Among World Citizens: 1820-1992”, American Economic Review, VOL. 92, no. 4, September 2002, pp. 727-744. F. Bourgignon also coauthored the first working paper of OECD Development Centre, joint with the late W. Branson and J. de Melo (1989), "Macroeconomic Adjustment and Income Distribution: A Macro-Micro Simulation Model," OECD Development Centre Working Papers No. 1.)
Faaland's presidency of the OECD Development Centre does not appear in any of the obituaries nor in his wiki page. It was a big misunderstanding and ended quickly. The shy, silent and distanced Norwegian despised the OECD and its ambassadors, who liked to hear themselves talk but understood little about development. This earned him a lot of sympathy from the staff; yet for his political survival at the OECD this attitude was fatal[9].
I myself
was sent out from Bonn for initially three years. I was asked in Paris to
publish on the subject of "Latin America's debt crisis and international
trade" - even upon request, the assignment was not made more specific.
Well...
After
publishing a first neo-classical childsplay (in the style of the exiled
Hungarian Bela Balassa) I discovered the obvious parallels between
hyperinflationary Latin America of the 1980s and post-war Germany of the 1920s.
The idea of catching up on the missing doctorate before my supposed return to
the BMWi quickly matured. Since Cologne could be quickly reached by train and
my sister lived there near the university, I contacted Prof. Gerhard Fels at the IW, who recommended
me to Prof. Hans Willgerodt and Ralph Anderegg.
I literally
threw myself into the post-war literature on the German reparations problem. That the German transfer problem had many more
facets than just the foreign exchange problem (in the form of worsened terms of
trade) as emphasised by the Keynes/Ohlin
debate, that is what I learned especially in the writings of Fritz Machlup and Wilhelm Röpke. Like the Germans forty years earlier, the net
financial transfers of several emerging countries failed not because of the
dollar problem, but because of the internal budgetary problem of raising funds[10].
It was not easy to convince the development and finance directorates at the
OECD that indebted emerging countries did face a net financial transfer problem; my proposition was flatly rejected
on the (fancy) argument that debt service was not a capital flow.
Since Latin America's debt problem had so far been interpreted primarily as a dollar problem, especially in Washington, DC, the OECD version made a splash, fired mainly by William R. Cline (PIIE) as spelled out in his later review[11] and by Vito Tanzi (IMF). As fiscal director of the IMF, Vito Tanzi also had a bureaucratic interest in my work: this led to my own personal Tanzi effect. He invited me to an IMF lecture in Washington and to the 1988 Istanbul Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance. This was followed in 1989 by an invitation from the World Bank, just before the US Treasury presented the Brady Plan, in which I explored the question of how the industrialized countries were able to maintain their high public debt ratios without a crisis after World War II. More than thirty years later, the Covid crisis has brought the essay back up to date[12]. The Brady Plan gave rise to further work, joint with Bert Hofman (who would later rise at the World Bank to become its director for China), notably on the adjustment incentives of debt relief. See, e.g. Review of World Econmics, 1991).
With Axel van Trrotsenburg- who subsequently went to the World Bank - I published a first paper on the optimal monetary regime in East Asia in the same year[13]. Here, the policy background was pressure by the US Treasury excerted on the Asian NICs to appreciate their currencies and Bundesbank President Karl Otto Pöhl´s advice to peg to the Yen, on the pattern of the European Monetary System. From then, I was earmarked in some minds (such as the brilliant Jeffrey Shafer) to sabotage the US Treasury. The 1980s were the heydays of monetarists in two distinct varieties, domestic or international. The corollary were extreme prescriptions for currency regimes: domestic monetarists (Milton Friedman) opted for a pure float of the exchange rate, international monetarists (Robert Mundell) for a hard currency ped to an anchor currency. My stance was in between these extremes; my conviction owed a lot to East Asia´s growth performance based on reliably competitive real effective exchange rates and to work by Max Corden, Sebastian Edwards, Peter Kenen and John Williamson. Again, I got flak from the main OECD where New Zealand, a pure floater, had some influence, not least through the formidable John Llewellyn.
Just
Faaland's Dutch successor Louis Emmerij
(also "Big Louis") came from The Hague, where he had previously
served for nine years as Rector of the Institute of Social Studies, without
fulfilling his ambition to become Dutch Development Minister (like his PvdA
party friend Jan Pronk). Before that, Big Louis had earned merits at the ILO,
where he had headed the World Employment Program from 1971-76. Under Big Louis'
leadership, the concept of basic needs had been developed, a forerunner of the
Human Development Index later developed by UNDP head Mahbub Ul Haq, who shaped the development debate.
Emmerij
brought some interesting economists to the Centre (Eliana Cardoso with Rudi
Dornbusch; Jacques J. Polak; Keith B. Griffin). Rudi lobbied Peter Kenen to disseminate my
dissertation globally in a concentrated form as a Princeton Study in International Finance[14].
For Jacques Polak I became the in-house sparring partner of two OECD
publications, of considerable interest given Polak´s great influence at the
Fund[15].
Emmerij's
father had died in 1945 in the Dachau concentration camp[16].
As a German, I was treated quite reservedly by Big Louis for understandable
reasons, like I was previously treated by Just Faaland. My macro themes
"your pet subject" did not interest him very much either.
Nevertheless, I admired Big Louis for his alert intelligence and punctual
limited working hours. And I forgave the caviar
socialist for his feudal predilections; at noon he had his own chauffeur
drive him in the official car to the expensive country club in nearby Bois de Boulogne, where he liked to keep
court when the weather was good.
Either Louis
Emmerij seems to have left no lasting mark as Centre President or the OECD is sloppy in keeping up its records on the internet, so much institutional memory gets erased. Neither the
OECD's iLibrary nor the OECD Development Centre lists Big Louis, which could suggest that
he did not leave behind any enduring conference volumes. In fact, he would start a very fruitful collaboration with Enrique Iglesisas at the IDB, which gave rise to a first joint IDB/Development Centre seminar in late 1990. (I will come back to those in the next post on the 1990s).
Big Louis made good personnel decisions, however. He also lured back David Turnham, who Ian Little had already brought along as a research assistant and who since the 1970s had been working for the World Bank. David was one of the first to address the problem of underemployment in poor countries. In 1988, the South African high flyer Ian Goldin was also hired (from Oxford U). He ran research on Changing Comparative Advantage in Food and Agriculture, to promote less protective agricultural policies in OECD countries. With the support of Dominique van der Mensbrugghe, a general equilibrium model saw the light: the Rural/Urban-North/South (RUNS) model. "Have model, will travel" (so David Turnham). Indeed, Ian did not stay long at the Centre (1988-92) as he was invited by Nelson Mandela to join his government at the helm of the state-owned Development Bank of Southern Africa. On that period, read Ian Goldin´s obituary of Mandela in the OECD Observer.
[1] The establishment of the OECD
Development Centre was proposed by US President John F. Kennedy in a speech to
the Canadian Parliament in Ottawa on 17 May 1961: https://youtu.be/tVO4HifEqEk
[2] In Germany (1976-1983), I had
four employers during a rather short period as a professional economist. See https://reibreisen.blogspot.com/2020/06/meine-deutschen-chefs-1976-1983.html. (available only in German)
[3] In multilateral
organizations, the double delegation problem (voter->government->IO)
complicates the principal-agent dilemma. Cf. Nielson, Parks & Tierney
(2017), „International organizations and development finance: introduction to
the special issue”, The Review of International Organizations , Vol. 12, pp.
157–169.
[4] For an appreciation of the
economist IMD Little, see C. Bliss and V. Joshi (2014). "Ian Malcolm David Little 1918–2012" (PDF). Biographical Memoirs
of Fellows of the British Academy. XIII: 317–318.
[5] As usual, Prof. Little did not
mince his words in his recollections. Therefore worth reading: Ian Little
(2002), „The Centre since the 1960s“, in Jorge Braga de
Macedo, Colm Foy and Charles P. Oman (eds.), Development
is Back, Paris: OECD Development Centre, 257-262.
[6] The German delegation to the
OECD had speculated in vain on a high post at the Centre. It was only when this
appointment fell through that she put pressure for my candidacy.
[8] Among his many OECD
bestsellers, the most cited is Angus Maddison (2006), The World Economy, Vol.1: A
Millenial Perspective; Vol. 2: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD
Development Centre.
[9] Since the OECD does not
cultivate its institutional memory very much, it does not pay tribute to former
Development Centre presidents. Cf. the Chr. Michelsen Institute (2017), In memory of Just Faaland , Bergen.
[10] Helmut
Reisen (1987), Über das Transferproblem hochverschuldeter
Entwicklungsländer, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, Baden-Baden. Extended OECD version Helmut Reisen
& Axel van Trotsenburg (1988), Developing Country Debt: The
Budgetary and Transfer Problem, Paris: OECD Development Centre.
[11] William R. Cline (1995), International Debt Reexamined,
Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, pp.151-153.
[12] Helmut Reisen (1989), “Public Debt, North and South”, Policy Research Working Paper
Series 253, The World Bank.
[13] Helmut Reisen & Axel van
Trotsenburg (1988), „Should the Asian NICs Peg to the
Yen?“, Intereconomics,
vol. 23(4), pages 172-177, July.
[14] Helmut Reisen (1989), "Public Debt, External Competitiveness, And Fiscal Discipline In
Developing Countries,"
Princeton Studies in International
Economics 66, International Economics Section, Departement of Economics
Princeton University.
[16] Richard Jolly (2020), „Louis Emmerij obituary“, The Guardian, 27
January.
No comments:
Post a Comment