Considering the wide range of
scenarios for future developing-country growth and poverty reduction, prudence
would suggest to approach strategic changes of multilateral concessional
windows with a precautionary, rather than a deterministic, perspective to
enable flexible institutional response. That perspective should not only watch
the prospect of future graduation for countries today eligible for multilateral
soft windows, but also the prospect of reverse graduation resulting from
disasters, military conflict and governance failures[1].
Don´t allow the shareholders of multilateral soft windows “to sleepwalk into
the future” (Séverino & Moss, 2012)[2]
- yes; but don´t either allow them to ignore the option value of preserving the
financial and institutional strength of the soft windows by “declaring success”
and letting them shrink. After all, the
configuration of poverty scenarios and strategic options is such that there may
be a multilateral donor dilemma; but then there may be not... Consider Table 1 and try to attach
probabilities to the sum of outcomes that would constitute a donor dilemma
(left column) and to those where a donor dilemma would not exist (right
column).
Table 1: When Do We Have a Donor Dilemma?
|
|
Poverty
Gap/Donor Dilemma
|
|
Poverty Gap/No Donor Dilemma
|
|
1
|
Closed
in LICs & MICs
|
4
|
In
´stable´ LICs
|
|
2
|
Only in ´fragile´
LICs
|
5
|
In MICs with little
capacity for
redistribution
|
|
3
|
Also
in MICs with good
capacity
for redistribution
|
6
|
Redefinition
of eligibility status
and
of IFI mandates
|
Case 1: There
will be a multilateral donor dilemma when “we beat” poverty by 2025 without
changing IFI mandates. History suggests that the absence of institutional
change is unlikely for a number of reasons: first, the concept of
ODA-eligibility is ´elusive´ (Schlögl, 2013)[3]
as it does not have hard legal force; second, there have been exceptions (such
as currently the small islands, or Israel before); third, rent-seeking by
affected bureaucracies; and fourth, divergent paradigms with respect to poverty
(absolute vs relative).
Case 2: This
is the old, Paul Collier´s (2007) Bottom
Billion. Should poverty be
concentrated in a few countries labelled ´fragile´ by 2025[4],
aid volume targeted at poverty would have to shrink as the absorptive capacity
in those countries is too limited relative to current aid volumes. Except for
small island economies, there are 25 countries currently in that category, of
which 20 in Africa (OECD, 2014, The Where
of…, op.cit, Figure 2), with only 24% of the world poor living there.
Moreover, one third of this country group is considered resource rich,
intensifying the donor dilemma.
Case 3: It
cannot be excluded that the majority of the world´s poor will live in MICs by
2025. This is the new, Andy Sumner´s (2013)[5]
Bottom Billion. They constitutes
another side of the donor dilemma, mainly because of the widespread presumption
that MICs can take care of themselves, given their tax and redistribution
capacity, but also their other assets (FX reserves, sovereign wealth funds) and
their own donor activities.
Case 4: This
is the ´easy´ case for donors, as the category of ´stable´ LICs is thought to
have the governance and institutions that allow for efficient aid allocation
and absorption. The problem is that there are not many currently in that
category, according to the OECD: 15. But it could be that aid to the fragile
LICs catalyzes governance reform so that some of these countries move to ´stable´
before graduation.
Case 5: This
is the ´uneasy´ case for donors as it has become increasingly difficult to
explain to voters at home. Still, a large part of chronic poverty is likely to
be located in MICs that have only little capacity to redistribute. These are
the MICs with annual consumption per capita under $2,000; the tax burdens required to
close the national poverty gaps are prohibitive in these countries, according
to Ravaillon (2012). Kanbur and Sumner (2011)[6]
provide some arguments for aid to poor people in MICs rather than only to poor
countries: chronic poverty calls for common humanity[7];
concessional finance facilitates working on GPGs with strong externalities for
donors; and creating a common knowledge base for policy lessons to combat
poverty in poor countries. While uneasy for donors, these MICs do not
necessarily constitute a donor dilemma.
Case 6: Strategic
options exist for the shareholders of IFIs to attenuate the donor dilemma (if
there is one) up to 2025. These options will be shortly presented and discussed:
complementing/redefining the current IDA cutoff (GNI/capita); introducing
subsovereign allocation; smoothening transition periods from IDA-only via blend
status to IBRD-only (and correspondingly for the other MDBs); and opening
the soft windows for global public goods.
[1]
For example, since IDA´s inception, 36 countries have graduated, of which 11
became ´reverse graduates´ subsequently; another 17 IDA-only countries were, at
one point in time, assessed as creditworthy for IBRD financing and classified
as a blend country, but subsequently reversed to IDA-only status. For detail,
see IDA (2012), “Review of IDA´s Graduation Policy”, World Bank: Washington,
DC, October.
[2]
Jean-Michel Séverino and Todd Moss (2012), Soft Lending Without Poor Countries,
Center for Global Development: Washington, DC, October.
[3] Lukas
Schlögl (2013), The End of Poverty Alleviation? Effects of Shifting
Global Wealth on Aid Allocation and Graduation from Foreign Aid Eligibility, Universität Wien.
[4] As
defined by OECD (2014), The Where of
Development Finance, OECD: Paris, January.
[5] Andy
Sumner (2013), „Where
Do The Poor Live?”, World Development,
Vol. 40(5), pp. 865-877.
[6] Kanbur,
Ravi and Andy Sumner (2011), “Poor
Countries or Poor People? Development Assistance and the New Geography of
Global Poverty”, CEPR Discussion Paper 8489, CEPR: London.
[7]
The German philosopher Thomas Pogge (Yale) is a prominent representative of
that school of thought which has challenged Rawls´
A Theory of Justice that applies only within a nation state: See Ravi
Kanbur (2014), Resetting
IDA’s Graduation Policy, Cornell University, mimeo, January.