The Fund´s traditional focus on non-concessional
short-term programs to restore macroeconomic balance ended in the mid-1980s[1]. Heavy foreign debt and low economic
performance were found to preclude most LICs from borrowing at the usual non-concessional
IMF terms. The IMF therefore responded by introducing new facilities designed
specifically for LICs. The public quest for more country ownership and for a
strengthened focus on poverty reduction led in 1999 to the Poverty Reduction
and Growth Facility (PRGF). To increase and improve financial support to low-income
countries, creditors also resolved to make greater efforts to restore debt
sustainability and fiscal space in LICs by providing comprehensive debt relief,
first under the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative[2].
Multilateral debt could for the first time be written down, including debts
owed to the IMF itself. In 2005, the IMF approved the Multilateral Debt Relief
Initiative (MDRI) to provide significant further debt reduction beyond the HIPC
Initiative.
The 2009 reforms created a new
architecture of concessional facilities aimed at providing more flexible and
tailored support to meet the diverse needs of LICs. Since then, the Extended Credit Facility (ECF) the main
concessional tool for addressing protracted balance of payments problems. The
ECF is the most important of three concessional lending windows that are part
of the Poverty Reduction and Growth
Trust (PRGT). The Standby Credit Facility (SCF) was created to provide
support to LICs with short-term balance of payments needs, with the possibility
of using it on a precautionary basis. The Rapid Credit Facility (RCF) was
created to provide rapid low-access financing with limited conditionality.
Interest rates were reduced to zero on all concessional facilities as a
temporary measure in response to the crisis—a measure that has been extended
through end-2014.
Figure 1: Projected Number of Countries Eligible for
PRGT
The number of LICs eligible for
support from concessional IMF lending is projected to drop from currently slightly
above 70 to 50 by 2050 (Figure 5.1.) Future demand for IMF concessional lending
is projected by the Fund to remain elevated, despite real GDP growth for the
median LIC projected to grow at around 6 percent. However, strong expected
growth performance notwithstanding, vulnerabilities remain elevated in LICs,
suggesting the potential need for continued strong IMF support over the medium
term. Over the past two years, many LICs have reduced fiscal space and larger
current account deficits than prior to the crisis. Increasing financial and trade
openness and higher GDP will translate a given shock into higher concessional
financing needs until graduation, according to the IMF (OP#277, p. 32).
Moreover, particularly fragile states and those emerging from conflict, may
still require repeated RCF and ECF support before they are able to strengthen
their macroeconomic positions sufficiently that they no longer require
longer-term Fund financing (p.33). For the period 2013-35, the IMF (OP#277,
Figure 4.2.) projects the average annual demand for PRGT lending at between SDR
1.3bn and 1.7bn ($2.01bn, resp. $2.63bn).
What are the specific strategic
options for the next decade? For the Fund´s concessional engagement with low
income countries, three strategic options seem particularly worthy of further
debate:
- Increasing the scope for blending subsidized resources from the PRGT with general resources of the Fund in order to preserve concessional resources for the poorer LICs. Growing divergence of economic performance and political stability among low income countries should be reflected in a higher share of blend finance going forward[3]. Another important argument for raising the amount of blend finance to LICs is the budget constraints of the traditional donor countries: blending means more leverage per given resources[4]. Currently, PRGT-eligible members are presumed to blend if (i) their per capita GNI exceeds 100 percent of the IDA operational cutoff; or if (ii) their per capita GNI exceeds 80 percent of the IDA operational cutoff and they also have market access as defined below[5]; and (iii) they are not at high risk of debt distress or in debt distress. Increasing the share of blending could be defined as a function of sustained past and prospective future access to non-concessional lending from capital markets and official lenders, including emerging partners; median (not mean) or median/mean per capita GNI, with various percentage points relative to the IDA cutoff, below or above.
- It is recommended[6] to bring the average grant element in IMF concessional lending to PRGT-only countries closer to those of the soft windows of the MDBs. Until recently, contracting of non-concessional debt, i.e., debt with a grant element of less than 35 percent was prohibited in IMF-supported programs in LICs; while contracting of concessional debt, i.e. debt with a grant element of at least 35 percent, was not subject to any limit. Mainly due to shorter maturities (10 v 40 years), IMF lending has a lower grant element (only now at ca. 35%)[7] than IDA lending (61.1%). The Fund cannot provide outright grants as these would undermine its revolving nature. Raising the IMF grant element would be effected by longer grace and maturity periods in IMF lending; it would also require more resources as the IMF lending capacity would be cut, but this capacity effect could be compensated by a lower number of PRGT-only eligible countries. Should scenarios implying a lower number of PRGT-only countries not materialize, more resources would be needed, however[8].
- Disaster-poverty hotspots - as identified by ODI (2013)[9] – would particularly benefit from adding an insurance-type instrument with ex ante qualification criteria to the PRGT lending facilities. The grace period for PRGT lending, currently a fixed period of five years, could be complemented by a five‐year floating grace period, which the country could use whenever it was hit by a predetermined natural shock to exports, GDP, or programmed aid. When LICs can chose between counter cyclical credit lines or disaster-insurance, they will opt for the latter the larger the possible loss (in terms of GDP, say), the lower the cost of insurance, and the higher interest rate the country pays when it borrows. To be sure, current PRGT-refinancing cost can only rise (not fall any longer) up to 2025 as they are close to the zero bound. Projecting rising interest rates, a facility with no initial grace period but with a five‐year floating grace period, which the country could use whenever it was hit by a shock, would become increasingly attractive[10].
So far, judging from the
publications that the Fund puts in a very transparent manner on its website,
the strategic considerations with respect to its future as a source of concessional
finance leave the impression that their coordination with other multilateral soft-finance
windows ncould be improved upon. This might hold especially when the Fund´s
grant element for PRGT-only countries is raised by lengthened lending
maturities, bringing its profile closer to those of the multilateral
development banks. Different ministerial tutelage, however, will be a stumbling
block to closer coordination.
[1] For more
historical detail on the IMF history of concessional finance, see Yasemin Bal
Gündüz et al. (2013), The Economic
Impact of IMF-Supported Programs in Low-Income Countries, IMF
Occasional Papers #277.
[2] HIPC trust
funds are separate from PRGT funds and will not be discussed here.
[3] Find a detailed discussion of blending options in IMF (2013), Review Of Facilities For Low-Income
Countries— Proposals For Implementation, March 2013
[4] The use of windfall profits from gold sales was an important source
for subsidizing the PRGT in the recent past. The IMF Executive Board took a
decision in September 2012 that would increase annual lending capacity to LICs
to an estimated SDR 1.25 billion on a self-sustained basis (i.e., without a
further infusion of resources to the PRGT). Absent a persistent change in
trends, this is sufficient to meet the average projected base level demand for
PRGT resources over the next 20 years, according to OP#277. Note, however, that
an earlier IMF review had been less optimistic: “Updated longer-term demand
projections suggest that LICs’ financing needs will outstrip the PRGT’s lending
capacity.” IMF (2012), Review of
Facilities for Low-Income Countries, June, p.18. That review produced a
wider margin of PRGT-demand for the same period than the recent OP#277, from
SDR 1.2bn to 1.9bn, which may indicate some internal vetting.
[5] The 80%
rule currently applies to India and Pakistan (interview with C. Mumssen, 6th
March, 2014).
[6] See also Matthew Martin and Alison Johnson (2004), The Role of Multilateral Grants in Financing
the MDGs, Commission for Africa Background Paper, Development Finance
International: London, September.
[7] IMF, Debt limits in Fund-Supported Programs: Proposed New
Guidelines, August 2009 calculated an average grant element of 27.6%, which has
been raised to 35% (C. Mumssen, 6th March, 2014.
[8] The formula to compute the budget implications is given by: Grant Element
(GE), % = 100(FV – NPV)/FV => NPVIMF/IDA = GEIMF/IDA
x NPVIMF =NPVIDA .
[9] ODI (2013),
“The geography of climate change, disasters
and climate extremes in 2030”, Overseas Development Institute: London.
[10] This facility would follow the example set by the French Agence
Française de Développement initially suggested by D. Cohen, P. Jacquet and H. Reisen
(2006), After
Gleneagles: What Role for Loans in ODA?, OECD Development Centre Policy
Brief No. 31, OECD: Paris, December. For how to apply the AFD loans to the IMF
concessional facilities, see Eduardo Borensztein et al (2008), “Aid
Volatility and Macro Risks in Low-Income Countries”, OECD Development
Centre Working Paper No. 273, OECD: Paris, June.
Thank you for pointing me to this post, Helmut. Kind regards, Jean-Philippe
ReplyDelete