Would a stronger core budget funding of the World Health Organisation and less
dominance of earmarked funding of global health spending have prevented the
current rapid spread of Ebola? This daring thesis was expressed last week at a fascinating
workshop, sponsored by the Swiss Network for International Studies (SNIS), at Zurich University,
on the “Proliferation of Multilateral Funds”. WHO Director Dr. Margaret Chan
recently complained: “My budget [is] highly earmarked, so it is driven by what
I call donor interests”.
Earmarked multilateral funding has spread like
a virus in recent decades, with earmarking defined in thematic, geographic and/or
institutional terms. Bilateral donors channel earmarked funds to multilateral
development agencies that implement activities for them, but without allowing
these agencies to use the funds at their own discretion. The hybrid funding
mechanism is often dubbed multi-bi aid. The Figure[1]
below shows that earmarked multilateral funding has really won traction,
ironically, since the Paris Declaration 2005 that sought to turn aid delivery
less burdensome for the recipients, including by simplifying delivery channels.
It is based on 680 (!) distinct multilateral development organisations (much
more than the 280 ODA eligible counted by the OECD Report on Multilateral Aid).
With a volume of 19 billion USD in 2012, multi-bi aid today amounts to almost
60 percent of the volume of multilateral aid.
Figure: Multi-bi aid relative to multilateral
contributions,
in percent, 1990 - 2012
Source: Reinsberg et
al. (2014)
Viewed from a principal-agent perspective (with the donors as principals and the
multilaterals as agents), the higher share of non-core budgets in multilateral
organizations has gone along the move from collective
principals to multiple principals,
from member country groupings with largely homogenous preferences to groupings
with heterogeneous policy goals. Applied to the UN system, the US called the
shots after WWII based on its Western European and Latin American allies in
what was then a much smaller country grouping. To the extent that the UN
enlarged and raised its member base, the US, the UK and other leading countries
lost the majority. This explains the start and rise of voluntary multilateral
aid funding from the 1960s. Multiple principals have multiple interests that
they see better implemented in earmarked rather than general policy programs.
The recent rapid rise of the share of earmarked
contributions to multilateral aid over the past two decades, however, needs
further explanation. The rise is closely correlated with the establishment of
so-called trust funds, either umbrella funds with many donors or, somehow
perversely, single-donor funds. Mid-2013, the overall number of active trust
funds at the World Bank was more than 900(!).
So what makes trust funds attractive to donor
governments? First, the voluntary nature of multi-bi contributions to trust
funds provides more flexibility as they are typically independent of long-term
agreements at the international level (such as the three-year IDA replenishment
rounds). In contrast, they are released on a short-term basis. Second, governance and management structures can
be designed in ways that may also allow for leverage from private charities, foundations,
firms, or charities. Third, and perhaps most importantly, trust funds
(especially the rapidly rising single-donor funds) can be tailored to the (ever
changing) policy priorities of donor governments. Arguably, the vehicle is well
suited to mobilise resources to fund global public goods – under the condition
that these resources are complementary (which seems largely the case).
What then has made multilateral trust funds so
much more attractive? Two further papers presented at the SNIS workshop provide
some convincing hints[2].
First, the simple existence of trust funds influences the aid allocation by
donors across available channels: the possibility of earmarking multilateral
aid decreases donors' contributions to the multilateral's discretionary core
budget and the amount of bilateral aid. Second, the existence of earmarking may
also stimulate some active agents (the boss or management team of an
international organisation) to enlarge their fiefdoms; I for one have worked in
such an organization. Third, policy priorities do change but multilaterals can
be very slow to accommodate those changes, partly for bureaucratic inertia but
also for perfectly justified governance rules; the more this results in
incompatible goals between donors and agencies, the higher will be the
incentive to create trust funds and earmark funds. Finally, the same impact
will occur to the extent that policy priorities become more heterogeneous
across donors.
The demise of the United States as the
benevolent Kindleberger-type hegemon in a multipolar world and the rise of the emerging donors such as
China would lead to predict that there will be more, not less, earmarked
multilateral funding in the future. The multilateral donor chaos is alive and
kicking[3].
[1] Modified from and based on a
forthcoming article by Reinsberg, Michaleowa and Eichenbauer (2014), “The rise
of multi-bi aid and the proliferation of trust funds”, Handbook of Development Economics 2014.
[2] Eichenbauer and Hug (2014), “The politics
of special-purpose trust funds”, unpublished, Heidelberg University and
Université de Génève; Reinsberg, Michaelowa, and Knack (2014), “Which donors,
which funds? The choice of multilateral funds by bilateral donors at the World
Bank”, unpublished, University of Zurich and World Bank.
[3] Reisen (2010), "The multilateral
donor non-system: towards accountability and efficient role assignment,"
Economics - The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, vol. 4(5), pages 1-22.
No comments:
Post a Comment